Tax Avoidance and Tax Evasion Explained and Exemplified

Law Of Diminishing Marginal Returns Definition - Tax Avoidance and Tax Evasion Explained and Exemplified

Good morning. Today, I learned about Law Of Diminishing Marginal Returns Definition - Tax Avoidance and Tax Evasion Explained and Exemplified. Which may be very helpful for me therefore you. Tax Avoidance and Tax Evasion Explained and Exemplified

Introduction

What I said. It isn't the conclusion that the actual about Law Of Diminishing Marginal Returns Definition. You check this out article for info on what you wish to know is Law Of Diminishing Marginal Returns Definition.

Law Of Diminishing Marginal Returns Definition

There is a clear-cut inequity in the middle of tax avoidance and tax evasion. One is legally appropriate and the other is an offense. Unfortunately any way many consultants even in this country do not understand the inequity in the middle of tax avoidance and tax evasion. Most of the planning aspects that have been recommend by these consultants often fall into the category of tax evasion (which is illegal) and so tends to put clients into a risky situation and also diminish the value of tax planning.

This may be one of the prime reasons where clients have lost faith in tax planning consultants as most of them have often recommend dubious systems which are clearly under the category of tax evasion.

In this part I contribute some examples and case studies (including legal cases) of how tax evasion (often recommend by consultants purporting to be specialists in tax planning) is undertaken not only in this country but in many parts of the world. It is true that many people do not like to pay their hard-earned money to the government. any way doing this in an illegal manner such as by tax evasion is not the answer. Good tax planning involves tax avoidance or the discount of the tax incidence. If this is done properly it can save substantial amounts of money in a legally appropriate way. This part also highlights some practical examples and case studies (including legal) of tax avoidance.

Why Governments Need Your Taxes (Basic Economic Arguments)

Income tax the biggest source of government funds today in most countries is a comparatively new invention, probably because the thought of every year revenue is itself a contemporary concept. Governments preferred to tax things that were easy to portion and on which it was thus easy to theorize the liability. This is why early taxes concentrated on tangible items such as land and property, corporeal goods, commodities and ships, as well as things such as the estimate of windows or fireplaces in a building. In the 20th century, particularly the second half, governments colse to the world took a growing share of their country's national revenue in tax, in general to pay for increasingly more expensive defense efforts and for a contemporary welfare state. Indirect tax on consumption, such as value-added tax, has become increasingly important as direct taxation on revenue and wealth has become increasingly unpopular. But big differences among countries remain. One is the wide level of tax. For example, in United States tax revenue amounts to colse to one-third of its Gdp (gross domestic product), whereas in Sweden it is closer to half.

Others are the preferred methods of collecting it (direct versus indirect), the rates at which it is levied and the definition of the tax base to which these rates are applied. Countries have separate attitudes to progressive and regressive taxation. There are also big differences in the way accountability for taxation is divided among separate levels of government. Arguably agreeing to the discipline of economics any tax is a bad tax. But communal goods and other government activities have to be paid for somehow, and economists often have strong views on which methods of taxation are more or less efficient. Most economists agree that the best tax is one that has as minuscule impact as possible on people's decisions about either to undertake a productive economic activity. High rates of tax on labour may discourage people from working, and so ensue in lower tax revenue than there would be if the tax rate were lower, an idea captured in the Laffer curve in economics theory.

Certainly, the marginal rate of tax may have a bigger ensue on incentives than the wide tax burden. Land tax is regarded as the most productive by some economists and tax on expenditure by others, as it does all the taking after the wealth creation is done. Some economists favor a neutral tax system that does not work on the sorts of economic activities that take place. Others favor using tax, and tax breaks, to guide economic performance in ways they favor, such as to minimize pollution and to growth the attractiveness of employing people rather than capital. Some economists argue that the tax system should be characterized by both horizontal equity and vertical equity, because this is fair, and because when the tax system is fair people may find it harder to explicate tax evasion or avoidance.

However, who ultimately pays (the tax incidence) may be separate from who is initially charged, if that man can pass it on, say by adding the tax to the price he charges for his output. Taxes on companies, for example, are all the time paid in the end by humans, be they workers, customers or shareholders. You should note that taxation and its role in economics is a very wide branch and this book does not address the issues of taxation and economics but rather tax planning to enhance your economic position. any way if you are concerned in insight the role of taxation in economics you should consult a good book on economics which often talks about the impact of separate types of taxation on the economic activities of a nation of society.

Tax Avoidance and Evasion

Tax avoidance can be summed as doing all things possible within the law to sell out your tax bill. Learned Hand, an American judge, once said that there is nothing sinister in so arranging one's affairs as to keep taxes as low as possible as nobody owes any communal duty to pay more than the law demands. On the other hand tax evasion can be defined as paying less tax than you are legally obliged to. There may be a thin line in the middle of the two, but as Denis Healey, a former British chancellor, once put it, "The inequity in the middle of tax avoidance and tax evasion is the thickness of a prison wall." The courts identify the fact that no taxpayer is obliged to dispose his/her affairs so as to maximize the tax the government receives. Individuals and businesses are entitled to take all valid steps to minimize their taxes.

A taxpayer may lawfully dispose her affairs to minimize taxes by such steps as deferring revenue from one year to the next. It is valid to take all available tax deductions. It is also valid to avoid taxes by making charitable contributions. Tax evasion, on the other hand, is a crime. Tax evasion typically involves failing to article income, or improperly claiming deductions that are not authorized. Examples of tax evasion comprise such actions as when a contractor "forgets" to article the Lkr 1, 000,000 cash he receives for construction a pool, or when a firm owner tries to deduct Lkr 1, 000,000 of personal expenses from his firm taxes, or when a man falsely claims she made charitable contributions, or significantly overestimates the value of property donated to charity.

Similarly, if an estate is worth Lkr 5,000,000 and the executor files a false tax return, improperly omitting property and claiming the estate is only worth Lkr 100,000, thus owing much less in taxes. Tax evasion has an impact on our tax system. It causes a significant loss of revenue to the society that could be used for funding improvements in health, education, and other government programs. Tax evasion also allows some businesses to gain an unfair advantage in a contentious store and some individuals to not meet their tax obligations. As a result, the burden of tax not paid by those who pick to evade tax falls on other law abiding taxpayers.

Examples of tax evasion are: ï?~ Failing to utter chargeable revenue ï?~ Claiming deductions for expenses that were not incurred or are not legally deductible ï?~ Claiming input earnings for goods that Value Added Tax (Vat)has not been paid on ï?~ Failing to pay the Paye (pay as you earn a form of with holding tax)installments that have been deducted from a payment, for example tax taken out of a worker's wages ï?~ Failing to lodge tax returns in an endeavor to avoid payment. The following are some signs that a man or firm may be evading tax: ï?~ Not being registered for Vat despite clearly exceeding the threshold ï?~ Not charging Vat at the spoton rate ï?~ Not wanting to issue a receipt ï?~ Providing false invoices ï?~ Using a false firm name, address, or taxpayers identification estimate (Tin) and Vat registration estimate ï?~ holding two sets of accounts, and ï?~ Not providing staff with payment summaries

Legal Aspects of Tax Avoidance and Tax Evasion Two normal points can be made about tax avoidance and evasion. First, tax avoidance or evasion occurs across the tax spectrum and is not peculiar to any tax type such as import taxes, stamp duties, Vat, Paye and revenue tax. Secondly, legislation that addresses avoidance or evasion must necessarily be imprecise. No prescriptive set of rules exists for determining when a singular arrangement amounts to tax avoidance or evasion. This lack of precision creates uncertainty and adds to compliance costs both to the branch of Inland revenue and the tax payer.

Definitions of Tax Mitigation Avoidance and Evasion It is impossible to express a spoton test as to either taxpayers have avoided, evaded or merely mitigated their tax obligations. As Baragwanath J said in Miller v Cir; McDougall v Cir: What is legitimate 'mitigation'(meaning avoidance) and what is illegitimate 'avoidance'(meaning evasion) is in the end to be decided by the Commissioner, the Taxation enumerate Authority and ultimately the courts, as a matter of judgment. Please note in the above statement the words are nothing else but as stated in judgment. any way there is a mix-up of words which have been clarified by the words in the brackets by me. Tax Mitigation (Avoidance by Planning) Taxpayers are entitled to mitigate their liability to tax and will not be vulnerable to the normal anti-avoidance rules in a statute. A article of tax mitigation was given by Lord Templeman in Cir v Challenge Corporate Ltd: revenue tax is mitigated by a taxpayer who reduces his revenue or incurs expenditure in circumstances which sell out his chargeable revenue or entitle him to discount in his tax liability.

Tax mitigation is, therefore, behavior which, without amounting to tax avoidance (by planning), serves to attract less liability than otherwise might have arisen. Tax Avoidance Tax evasion, as Lord Templeman has pointed out, is not mere mitigation. The term is described directly or indirectly by ï?~ Altering the incidence of any revenue tax ï?~ Relieving any man from liability to pay revenue tax ï?~ Avoiding, reducing or postponing any liability to revenue tax On an excessively literal interpretation, this coming could conceivably apply to mere mitigation, for example, to an individual's decision not to work overtime, because the supplementary revenue would attract a higher rate of tax. However, a best way of approaching tax avoidance is to regard it as an arrangement that, unlike mitigation, yields results that Parliament did not intend.

In Challenge Corporation Ltd v Cir, Cooke J described the ensue of the normal anti-avoidance rules in these terms: [It] nullifies against the Commissioner for revenue tax purposes any arrangement to the extent that it has a purpose or ensue of tax avoidance, unless that purpose or ensue is merely incidental. Where an arrangement is void the Commissioner is given power to adjust the chargeable revenue of any man affected by it, so as to counteract any tax advantage obtained by that person. Woodhouse J commented on the breadth of the normal anti-avoidance rule in the Challenge Corporation case, noting that Parliament had taken: The deliberate decision that because the qoute of definition in this elusive field cannot be met by expressly spelling out a series of detailed specifications in the statute itself, the interstices must be left for concentration by the judges.

Tax Evasion Mitigation and avoidance are concepts implicated with either or not a tax liability has arisen. With evasion, the starting point is all the time that a liability has arisen. The demand is either that liability has been illegitimately, even criminally been left unsatisfied. In Cir v Challenge Corporation Ltd, Lord Templeman said: Evasion occurs when the Commissioner is not informed of all the facts relevant to an assessment of tax. Innocent evasion may lead to a re-assessment. Fraudulent evasion may lead to a criminal prosecution as well as re-assessment.

The elements which can attract the criminal label to evasion were elaborated by Dickson J in Denver Chemical Manufacturing v Commissioner of Taxation (New South Wales): An intention to sustain facts lest the Commissioner should consider the taxpayer liable to a greater extent than the taxpayer is ready to concede, is show the way which if the ensue is to avoid tax would explicate looking evasion. Not all evasion is fraudulent. It becomes fraudulent if it involves a deliberate endeavor to cheat the revenue. On the other hand, evasion may exist, but may not be fraudulent, if it is the ensue of a genuine mistake. In order to prove the offence of evasion, the Commissioner must show intent to evade by the taxpayer. As with other offences, this intent may be inferred from the circumstances of the singular case. Tax avoidance and tax mitigation are mutually exclusive. Tax avoidance and tax evasion are not: They may both arise out of the same situation. For example, a taxpayer files a tax return based on the effectiveness of a transaction which is known to be void against the Commissioner as a tax avoidance arrangement.

A senior United Kingdom tax valid recently referred to this issue: If an 'avoidance' scheme relies on misrepresentation, deception and concealment of the full facts, then avoidance is a misnomer; the scheme would be more accurately described as fraud, and would fall to be dealt with as such. Where fraud is involved, it cannot be re-characterized as avoidance by cloaking the behavior with synthetic structures, contrived transactions and esoteric arguments as to how the tax law should be applied to the structures and transactions. Tax Avoidance in a policy Framework We now turn from the existing legal framework in the context of revenue tax to a possible policy framework for considering issues relating to tax avoidance generally. The questions thought about relevant to a policy diagnosis of tax avoidance are: What is tax avoidance? Under what conditions is tax avoidance possible? When is tax avoidance a 'policy problem? What is a sensible policy response to tax avoidance?

What is the value of, and what are the limitations of, normal anti-avoidance rules? The first two questions are discussed below What is Tax Avoidance? Finance literature may offer some advice to what is meant by tax avoidance in its definition of 'arbitrage'. Arbitrage is a means of profiting from a mismatch in prices. An example is looking and exploiting price differences in the middle of New Zealand and Australia in shares in the same listed company. A real value can be found in such arbitrage activity, since it spreads facts about prices. demand for the low-priced goods increases and demand for the costly goods decreases, ensuring that goods and resources are put to their best use. Tax arbitrage is, therefore, a form of tax planning. It is an performance directed towards the discount of tax. It is this thought of tax arbitrage that seems to constitute generally appropriate notions of what is tax avoidance. Activities such as giving money to charity or investing in tax-preferred sectors, would not fall into this definition of tax arbitrage, and thus would not be tax avoidance even if the performance were motivated by tax considerations. It has been noted that financial arbitrage can have a beneficial economic function. The same may be true of tax arbitrage, presuming that differences in taxation are deliberate government policy furthering economic efficiency.

It is possible that tax arbitrage directs resources into activities with low tax rates, as intended by government policy. It is also likely to ensure that investors in tax-preferred areas are those who can advantage most from the tax concessions, namely, those facing the top marginal tax rates. If government policy objectives are best achieved, tax arbitrage is in accordance with the government's policy intent. Tax avoidance, then, can be viewed as a form of tax arbitrage that is contrary to legislative or policy intent. What Makes Tax Avoidance Possible? The basic ingredients of tax arbitrage are the thought of arbitrage, and the possibilities of profiting from differentials that the thought of arbitrage implies. This definition leads to the view that three conditions need to be gift for tax avoidance to exist. A inequity in the productive marginal tax rates on economic revenue is required. For arbitrage to exist, there must be a price differential and, in tax arbitrage, this is a tax differential. Such tax differences can arise because of a variable rate structure, such as a progressive rate scale, or rate differences applying to separate taxpayers, such as tax-exempt bodies or tax loss companies.

Alternatively it can arise because the tax base is less than comprehensive, for example, because not all economic revenue is branch to revenue tax.

o An ability to exploit the inequity in tax by converting high-tax performance into low-tax performance is required. If there are differences in tax rates, but no ability to move from high to low-tax, no arbitrage is possible.
o Even if these two conditions are met, this does not make tax arbitrage and avoidance possible. The tax system may mix high and low-rate taxpayers. The high-rate taxpayer may be able to divert revenue to a low-rate taxpayer or turn highly-taxed revenue into a lowly-taxed form. But this is pointless unless the high-rate taxpayer can be recompensed in a lowly-taxed form for diverting or converting his or her revenue into a low-tax category. The revenue must come back in a low-tax form. The advantage must also exceed the transaction costs. This is the third significant health for tax arbitrage.
o Since all tax systems have tax bases (The thing or estimate to which a tax rate applies.

To acquire revenue tax, for example, you need a meaningful definition of income. Definitions of the tax base can vary enormously, over time and among countries, especially when tax breaks are taken into account. As a result, a country with a comparatively high tax rate may not have a high tax burden (Total tax paid in a period as a proportion of total revenue in that period. It can refer to personal, corporate or national income. ) if it has a more narrowly defined tax base than other countries. In new years, the political unpopularity of high tax rates has lead many governments to lower rates and at the same time broaden the tax base, often leaving the tax burden unchanged. )that are less than wide because of the impossibility of defining and measuring all economic income, tax arbitrage and avoidance is possible in tax systems. Examples of Tax Arbitrage/Avoidance The simplest form of arbitrage involves a family unit or a singular taxpayer. If that family unit or taxpayer faces differences in tax rates (condition 1 above), and health 2 above applies, then the third health automatically holds.

This end follows because people can all the time compensate themselves for converting or diverting revenue to a low tax rate. An example of such simple tax arbitrage spirited a family unit is revenue splitting through, for example, the use of family trust. An example of simple tax arbitrage spirited a singular taxpayer is a straddle whereby a dealer in financial assets brings send losses on, say shares, and defers gains while retaining an economic interest in the shares through use of options. Change pricing and thin capitalization practices through which non-residents minimize their tax liabilities are more sophisticated examples of the same principles. Multi-party arbitrage is more complex; the complexity is made significant by the need to meet health 3 above, that is, to ensure a net gain accrues to the high-rate taxpayer. In the simpler cases of multi-party revenue tax arbitrage, this process normally involves a tax-exempt (or tax-loss or tax-haven) entity and a taxpaying entity. revenue is diverted to the tax-exempt entity and expenses are diverted to the taxpaying entity. Finally, the taxpaying entity is compensated for diverting revenue and assuming expenses by receiving non-taxable revenue or a non-taxable benefit, such as a capital gain.

Over the years many have indulged in numerous examples of such tax arbitrage using elements in the legislation at the time. Examples are finance leasing, non-recourse lending, tax-haven(a country or designated zone that has low or no taxes, or very secretive banks and often a warm atmosphere and sandy beaches, which make it spirited to foreigners bent on tax avoidance and evasion ) 'investments' and redeemable preference shares. Low-tax policies pursued by some countries in the hope of attracting international businesses and capital is called tax competition which can contribute a rich ground for arbitrage. Economists normally favour competition in any form. But some say that tax competition is often a beggar-thy-neighbor policy, which can sell out another country's tax base, or force it to turn its mix of taxes, or stop it taxing in the way it would like.

Economists who favour tax competition often cite a 1956 article by Charles Tiebout (1924-68) entitled "A Pure system of Local Expenditures". In it he argued that, faced with a selection of separate combinations of tax and government services, taxpayers will pick to search where they get closest to the blend they want. Variations in tax rates among separate countries are good, because they give taxpayers more selection and thus more occasion of being satisfied. This also puts pressure on governments to be efficient. Thus measures to harmonize taxes are a bad idea. There is at least one big caveat to this theory. Tiebout assumed, crucially, that taxpayers are very movable and able to move to wherever their preferred blend of taxes and benefits is on offer.

Tax competition may make it harder to redistribute from rich to poor through the tax system by allowing the rich to move to where taxes are not redistributive. Tactics Used by Tax Evaders Moonlighting Tax evasion at its simplest level merely involves staying out of the tax system altogether. The revenue deploys small teams of volunteer officers to carry out guard to track down moonlighters. Early success was followed up by the deployment of compliance officers in virtually every tax office. revenue Investigation Officers routinely scan advertisements in local newspapers or shop windows and even before the advent of the contemporary personal computer they frequently had entrance to reverse telephone directories to track down moonlighters from bare telephone estimate details. They also study bank and other financial institutions deposit and loans databases, customs records, and star class hotel bookings for inexpressive functions and ceremonies to identify rich individuals who maybe evading taxes.

Non Extractive Fraud Alternatively it can arise because the tax base is less than comprehensive, for example, because not all economic revenue is branch to revenue tax. ï?~ An ability to exploit the inequity in tax by converting high-tax performance into low-tax performance is required. If there are differences in tax rates, but no ability to move from high to low-tax, no arbitrage is possible. ï?~ Even if these two conditions are met, this does not make tax arbitrage and avoidance possible. The tax system may mix high and low-rate taxpayers. The high-rate taxpayer may be able to divert revenue to a low-rate taxpayer or turn highly-taxed revenue into a lowly-taxed form. But this is pointless unless the high-rate taxpayer can be recompensed in a lowly-taxed form for diverting or converting his or her revenue into a low-tax category. The revenue must come back in a low-tax form. The advantage must also exceed the transaction costs. This is the third significant health for tax arbitrage. Since all tax systems have bases that are less than wide because of the impossibility of defining and measuring all economic income, tax arbitrage and avoidance is possible in tax systems. This involves behalf switches or timing differences, for example:

o Post dating Receipts
o Ante dating Expenditure
o inexpressive Reserves
o Incorrect accounting of transactions such as showing an revenue as a payable.
o Stock manipulation perhaps the most base place recipe seen in institution is the manipulation of stock to yield the desired "profit".

It is not unknown for the evaders' Accountant to be complex - putting at risk the livelihood and, if the estimate complex is significant, personal liberty! The most blatant case of this kind is where the Accountant virtually treated this as year end tax planning. Based upon the formal disclosures made by the evader under the Hansard policy to the Inland revenue (in which he implicated the Accountant and in relationship with an catalogue in a false name also his Bank Manager), the following scene can be recreated: "Studying the draft accounts the Accountant did a quick calculation to work out what range of figures could be used for end stock in hand without giving rise to suspicion. He then apparently discussed with the client the impact on net behalf of reducing end Stock.

Arrangements were then made for the audit to take place and in the meantime some stock was moved off site! "The Accountant and Bank boss who assisted the evader are both guilty of conspiracy to defraud - it matters not that they made no financial gain themselves. Extractive Fraud This might take the form of Suppressed receipts or inflated outgoings: Suppressed Receipts Typically these involve defected mainstream takings and often an undisclosed bank account. any way the more resourceful evader may take advantage of extra arrangements or unexpected receipts: Where the proprietor or director personally deals with some customers it may be possible for cheques to be made out in a manner which facilitates diversion. Alternatively cheque substitution may be used, such that the otherwise "off article sale" cheque is banked and an equivalent estimate of "on article cash" is extracted.

It is not unknown for late cash payment of reputation sales to bypass the bookkeeping system with the debt subsequently being written off as bad. Unexpected receipts all the time gift a good occasion for deflection. For example:

1. Scrap sales
2. Guarnatee or bad debt recoveries
3. Refunds, rebates or discounts
4. Returned goods sold for cash, disposal of fully written down assets and windfalls in general.

The evader may take advantage of a new firm opportunity, which remains hidden, and off record. Examples of this seen in institution include:

1. The dentist with three practices of which only two were discloses
2. The off article sale of hitherto obsolete car parts to the burgeoning first-rate car store Inflated Purchases & Expenses Where the ability to deflect receipts is too difficult the evader might draw cash from the firm bank catalogue and disguise such withdrawals as some form of legitimate firm expense. In institution this often involves the use of "ghost" employees or fictitious outgoings to cover such extractions. Fictitious outgoings have to hire the use of false invoices. These might take the form of altered invoices, photocopied or even scanned "blanked" versions of genuine invoices, completely bogus invoices or even blank invoices supplied by an associate.

Another coming seen in institution complex the use of a seemingly unconnected off shore firm to raise invoices for fictitious services. To hide the true ownership of the off shore firm the evader uses a "black hole" trust to hold the shares. Essentially this complex a compliant non-resident trustee and "dummy" settler - the trustee providing "stooge" directors as part of the arrangements.

Employment Tax Evasion Schemes Employment tax evasion schemes can take a collection of forms. Some of the more prevalent methods of evasion comprise pyramiding, employee leasing, paying employees in cash, filing false payroll tax returns or failing to file payroll tax returns. Pyramiding "Pyramiding" of employment taxes is a fraudulent institution where a firm withholds taxes from its employees but intentionally fails to remit them to the relevant departments. Businesses complex in pyramiding frequently file for bankruptcy to dismissal the liabilities accrued and then start a new firm under a separate name and begin a new scheme. Employment Leasing employee leasing is another legal firm practice, which is sometimes branch to abuse.

Employee leasing is the institution of contracting with exterior businesses to handle all administrative, personnel, and payroll concerns for employees. In some instances, employee-leasing fellowships fail to pay over to the authorities any portion of the collected employment taxes. These taxes are often spent by the owners on firm or personal expenses. Often the firm dissolves, leaving millions in employment taxes unpaid. Paying Employees in Cash Paying employees in whole or partially in cash is a base recipe of evading revenue and employment taxes resulting in lost tax revenue to the government and the loss or discount of future communal benefits. Filing False Payroll Tax Returns or Failing to File Payroll Tax Returns preparation false payroll tax returns understating the estimate of wages on which taxes are owed, or failing to file employment tax returns are methods generally used to evade employment taxes. Payments of Benefits These comprise free benefits such as personal entertainment, inordinate allowances for foreign travel, provision of educational schemes (foreign education) to only preferred employees, car and driver paid by firm etc are simple examples.

Conclusion

I hope that I have made clear the inequity in the middle of doing things right and nothing else but and in a fraudulent manner. either you are a taxpayer or a consultant it is important to make sure that you understand the nuances of good tax planning. Whilst it is understood that tax planning is becoming more difficult and there is only a thin line in the middle of what is right and wrong it obviously requires the devotee to do the needful. any way be faithful not to be tricked by those who claim to be experts in tax planning when they are mere computational experts.

I hope you will get new knowledge about Law Of Diminishing Marginal Returns Definition. Where you possibly can put to use within your life. And just remember, your reaction is passed about Law Of Diminishing Marginal Returns Definition.

0 comments:

Post a Comment